Safe to say Kwasi Kwarteng’s Growth Plan does not seem to have gone down very well.
The markets didn’t appear best pleased:
And neither did news outlets you might usually expect to be sympathetic, like the Wall Street Journal:
Of course, Twitter is even angrier.
The consensus view seems to be that the sudden drop in the pound reflected a complete lack of confidence in Truss and Kwarteng’s economic strategy. Their plan is taken to amount to a horribly expensive attempt to do frivolous, unfunded tax cuts for the rich at the worst possible moment — which is to say, while debt-financing an absolutely enormous energy subsidy, during a potential downturn, despite Britain having already used up most of its debt headroom on the pandemic.
So I appreciate this blog will not be popular. But I think this consensus gets it wrong.
It is wrong to suggest that the Growth Plan is to blame for the pound’s fall. And more damagingly, the centre-right press has chosen the utterly wrong moment to lose trust. Far from a disaster, Kwarteng’s plan could be transformative. It just needs to be delivered.
First things first:
Did Kwarteng destroy the pound?
To begin with some fairly basic economic theory: if currency traders expect bad news at some point in the future, they will expect the price of the pound to fall in future too. This means it’s in their interest to sell the pounds they own prior to that fall. As the supply of pounds on the market therefore goes up, the sale price falls, such that by the time whatever negative event they were anticipating then happens, prices hardly move at all. This is how things get ‘priced in’.
After the Growth Plan, the pound fell sharply. This implies traders reacted because they where surprised by something that happened around that time. The question is: what?
I tweeted this:
The enormous energy spending within the Growth Plan had already been announced, without causing a market reaction like this one. So that can’t have been the surprise.
What about the tax cuts? I don’t see how that makes sense either. Lowering taxes was the main distinguishing factor in the leadership election, and ‘wot won it’ for Truss. It would seem naive not to have expected her to deliver on them.
Perhaps then, as some suggested to me, the cuts were just much bigger than the market could have foreseen. To which I can only respond: really?
Here is a breakdown of the tax cuts in the Growth Plan, and their costings in year one.
These two were explicitly promised in the leadership election:
Reversing Sunak’s rise in national insurance contributions: £19bn
Reversing Sunak’s rise in corporation tax: £19bn
Meanwhile, these were announced for the first time in the Growth Plan:
Reversal of IR35 laws: £2bn
Abolishing the 45p income tax rate: £2bn
Increasing the stamp duty threshold: £1.7bn
Keeping the annual investment allowance at £1m: £1.3bn
£38bn of tax cuts had already been explicitly promised by Truss, but Truss’s victory triggered nothing like the same market reaction as we have now seen. So believing that the market’s reaction was caused by a ‘larger-than-expected’ tax cut package requires you to believe that the additional cuts, only worth around a quarter of that, were enough to produce a seismic market response.
I struggle to see how that makes much sense, although if this really did come as a surprise to some, then there is a fair critique to make here about communication strategy. In retrospect it would have been much better to signpost pre-announcement that Truss's major campaign commitments were going to be announced here and now, rather than later, and to reassure everyone that Kwarteng is still interested in fiscal responsibility. In other words, the Treasury's wonderfully euphemistic ‘Update on Growth Plan Implementation’ should have been released before, not after, the Growth Plan itself.
But suboptimal communication surely can't explain all of it. So what might?
My working theory is a less succinct and less well-explained version of this tweet:
What the Growth Plan represents is a fundamental reversal of the economic strategy of the last twelve years. Truss and Kwarteng want much looser fiscal policy, reined in by tighter monetary policy, as Kate Andrews reports. They are of the view that the British economy cannot go on like it is, with key public services getting ever worse while costing ever more money, productivity going nowhere, and growth completely flat. They believe this new strategy offers an escape from the spectacularly stagnant, slightly depressing status quo.
But the Bank’s monetary policy committee revealed last week it is yet to fully accept its role in all this. It raised interest rates by less than some expected, and, we might infer, by less than Truss and Kwarteng had been assuming too. This clearly reflects some lack of co-ordination between the Bank and the Treasury on their new roles. Understandable jitters on this point therefore might explain some of the market’s response.
Not all of it, granted. As Mike says, yields have surged, implying the market thinks the Bank will play its part next time around. Nonetheless, it seems reasonable to believe that markets fear that a historically fairly dove-ish MPC might remain more dove-ish than is necessary to make the fiscal strategy work and keep inflation reined in.
If the Bank can’t wholly be trusted to keep a lid on inflation, as Truss and Kwarteng want it to be, then how worried should we get? This comes to the latter part of Mike’s tweet. The market’s reaction suggests it is very worried. It is worried because it thinks the British economy has hardly any immediate ‘supply potential’ — meaning very little ability to absorb increases in demand without prices going up.
The exchange rate fell to the extent it did because Britain’s ability to supply more goods and services is exceptionally poor.
Which leads to a second question. In the long run, if this assessment of what caused our currency depreciation is correct, the way to fix it is to do two things:
Raise interest rates more quickly than the Bank is used to doing;
Radically reform the supply side of the British economy, so that it can cope with increases in demand much better.
One of these two is the purview of the Bank — though it now should be obvious why Truss once thought about reviewing the Bank’s mandate. But the other is entirely within the government’s control.
So the second question is this:
How badly does the government want economic growth?
If the Growth Plan’s spending decisions are to work without causing massive inflation and baking in the currency depreciation, they need to be met with a more ambitious supply-side reform agenda than anything we have seen for the last three decades.
Fortunately, the Growth Plan sets out exactly this. As very helpfully summarised by Ryan Bourne, it says that:
This is a long list, and even then it is only really a start on the work that the economy needs. It is also vague: it equivocates about the most important supply-side reform of all — housing reform — promising merely that more detail will be announced soon.
But it is a start. And if it is implemented properly (and followed up with more), it would allow Kwarteng’s plan to succeed, and with it, bring to end the awful bind that British policymaking has been stuck in since 2008.
The plan is therefore a do-or-die moment.
To commit to the Growth Plan’s tax-and-spend decisions without the structural reforms to go along with them would be a disaster. It would represent the worst of the status quo, but with a new layer of ‘bad’ added on top.
And there are lots of reasons for pessimism. Getting a supply-side reform through Parliament is much more difficult than doing new spending, especially with special interest groups doing their absolute utmost to block progress. Truss is already light on political capital, given how few MPs originally voted for her, and the response to our currency trouble will only have made that worse. Worst of all, there is very little time: it is less than two years until a general election.
Getting this right could hardly be more difficult. But doing what is right even when it is unpopular or poorly understood is often what defines the best Conservative MPs. Recall Geoffrey Howe:
And if they do get this right, despite everything in their way, the consequences will be vast.
Government after government has failed to do nearly enough about the supply side of the British economy. Reams have been written, far more eloquently than I can manage, about how this inaction has trapped us, time and time again, into choices we don’t want to have to make, on public services and elsewhere. It has trapped us into falling ever further behind America in our living standards. And it has nudged us into accepting relative decline as the norm and the future of Britain.
Until now, nobody has truly dared tackle this head-on. But we have finally found a PM and chancellor willing to do so. And yet for whatever reason — perhaps simply because we cannot get our heads around the reorganisation they have in mind — we are risking making it politically impossible before they have even begun to try.
In other words:
Do-or-die: it is a scary choice. But it is far better than having no choice at all.
Whether Kwarteng will be remembered as a Barber or a Howe is still to be decided. In taking this challenge on, he must have made himself one of the least popular people in Britain. And if he fails to follow through on the hard part, he might deserve to be.
But if he succeeds, he will have achieved, in under two years, more than any other chancellor has done in my lifetime. We will all owe him a strong pint.
This post marks the return of my blog, after a long period of procrastination. From approximately now on there should be much more regular content on the way. Please leave a comment or get in touch if you have any thoughts about this post, my blog in general, or anything else!
[EDIT: Substack told me this comment didn't actually get posted, so I wrote up the same ideas into an actual post. I'll leave this here just in case anyone's interested in the different ways I've framed it.]
I agree with you on this: 'If the Growth Plan’s spending decisions are to work ... they need to be met with a more ambitious supply-side reform agenda than anything we have seen for the last three decades.' And it seems Kwarteng and Truss, on some level, also agree with this. But that's the point - supply-side reform fits into their plan to 'finance' tax cuts and energy spending, rather than as the primary end-in-itself. Hence why, as you mention, the tax cuts and energy spending have received much closer attention to detail.
The problem is that nos. 10 and 11 have a very limited amount of political capital in the present moment, under pressure from the completely undisciplined parliamentary Tory party and from a major Labour polling lead. They are very likely to face rebellion or be forced to water down major policy commitments for political reasons - it's just the reality of the day. And thus priorities must be set: difficult trade-offs abound, and the government must decide which out of their basket of ideal policy changes matter most to them.
Kwarteng's decision to give so much detail to one side of the equation (viz., deficit spending) and be so vague as to the other (viz., deregulation) shows pretty clearly what this government's priorities are. He's emphasising this government's spending plans over its approach to supply. The problem is just that this is the wrong set of priorities, for *precisely* the reason you set out: Kwarteng's spending decisions simply do not work if he can't get supply-side changes through.
This matters because there's no evidence of a Truss plan on political economy here. I know you know this on housing, where the political economy factors are the *only* reason we've built so little. NIMBYs will NIMBY, there will be a Commons rebellion as there was under Johnson, and if reform is to pass it will require nerve from Truss and Kwarteng and a significant expenditure of political capital - yet they're already spending down all their political capital on tax cuts!
Supply-side reform without tax cuts, on the other hand, *would* work: there's no reason that building more housing would suddenly be a bad policy idea if we stuck 1pp back onto income tax. That's the way the priorities have to be. But the government have it completely backwards.
Your post seems to simply be abstracting all of the political difficulties away; but the political difficulties are the reason we have such low growth in the first place. If Truss and Kwarteng have the political chops to pull this off, maybe our future will all be rosy. But there is zero evidence that they have the political ability, and your post offers no reason to think that they can do it. Much more likely is that the political economy of supply-side reforms will eat them alive, and they'll have left Britain with a gaping deficit and a weak pound without any significant movement on growth.
Most of these supply side reforms seem either vague or weak beer